public inbox for bitcoindev@googlegroups.com
 help / color / mirror / Atom feed
From: Peter Todd <pete@petertodd.org>
To: Jonathan Levin <jonathan.levin@sant.ox.ac.uk>
Cc: bitcoin-research@lists.cs.princeton.edu,
	"bitcoin-development@lists.sourceforge.net"
	<bitcoin-development@lists.sourceforge.net>
Subject: Re: [Bitcoin-development] Economics of information propagation
Date: Wed, 23 Apr 2014 11:05:55 -0400	[thread overview]
Message-ID: <20140423150555.GE19430@savin> (raw)
In-Reply-To: <52CDA01B-13BF-4BB8-AC9A-5FBBB324FD15@sant.ox.ac.uk>

[-- Attachment #1: Type: text/plain, Size: 8942 bytes --]

On Mon, Apr 21, 2014 at 01:30:28AM +0000, Jonathan Levin wrote:

CC'ing bitcoin-research - may be more appropriate to move the discussion
there as this discussion is delving into future scenarios.

> Hi all,
> 
> I am a post-graduate economist writing a paper on the incentives of mining. Even though this issue has been debated in the forums, I think it is important to get a sense of the magnitude of the incentives at play and determine what implications this has for the transaction fee market.
> 
> As it has been pointed out before the marginal cost for miners does not stem from the private cost of the miner validating the signature and including it in the list of transactions in the block but rather the increased probability that the block will be orphaned as a result of slower propagation. Gavin did some back of the envelope worst case calculations but these overstated the effect of propagation delay. The reason being the 80ms additional time to reach 50% of the network is spread throughout the time that it takes to reach 50% of the network. During this time miners are notified about the block and treat it as the longest chain and hence are no longer mining with the aim to produce a competing block. 
> 
> I am looking to calculate the change in the curvature of the probability mass function that a block hears about my block in any given second as a function of the block size. Although there is likely to be significant noise here, there seems to be some stable linear relationships with the time that it takes to reach different quartiles. Has anyone done this? I have used some empirical data that I am happy to share but ideally I would like analytical solutions.
> 
> Following Peter Todd, I also find the concerning result that propagation delays results in increasing returns to higher shares of the hashing power. Indeed it may well be in the interest of large pools to publish large blocks to increase propagation delays on the network which would increase orphan rates particularly for small miners and miners that have not invested in sufficient bandwidth / connectivity. If a small miner hears about a block after 4.5 seconds on average there is a 0.7% chance that there is already a block in circulation.  Large miners can increase the time that it takes for small miners to hear about blocks by increasing the size of their blocks. For example if the time that it takes for a small miner to hear about the block goes to 12 seconds there is a 2 percent chance there is already a block in circulation for the small miner. There is also a 1.2% chance that there will be a competing block published after a small miner propagates in the time that it gets to full propagation. Am I getting this right that the probability of a miner’s block being orphaned is comprised of the probability that the miner was not the first to find a valid block and the probability that given they are first, someone else in the absence of hearing about it finds a competing valid block. 
> 
> One question is: Are orphans probabilistic and only resolved after hearing about a new block that lengthens the chain or is there a way to know in advance?

They're probabilistic; mining is progress free so per unit hashing power
every miner has an equal chance of finding a block. As for resolution,
well, currently nodes (and miners) mine on the block they saw first; if
they learn about another block at the same height they stick to the
block they are already mining on. First seen at same height is probably
generally economically rational as the first block you see probably
propagated to the most nodes, although tweaks to that are probably
possible.

> Is it frowned upon to mine on top of a block that you have just found even though it is very likely going to end up an orphan?

Not at all, in fact mining on top of the block is the best thing to do
because it *prevents* your block from ending up as an orphan. Basically
imagine I find block b1a, and you find conflicting block b1b. What I
need to do is find block b2a, which is on top of b1a, before you find
block b1b to avoid my block being orphaned. The best way to do that is
mining on top of my block - that's what's most rational for me.

> Would be happy to share the draft form of the paper and receive any feedback.

Sure thing.

> Finally, at coinometrics we are working on a modified client to capture information on network propagation and would invite any suggestions of any other useful statistics that would be useful in the development of software. 


So looking at the replies your post got in the past few days it looks
like there's some misinformation going around. First of all is the
question of how harmful it is if miners mine on top of blocks that they
haven't actually validated, and yes, that's extremely harmful. For
instance if I were an attacker I could mine an invalid block that makes
coins out of thin air and use it to defraud SPV-wallet-using clients;
everyone who is mining without validating is helping me succesfully pull
off that attack by increasing the chance I'll get enough confirms to
trick my target into thinking the coins are real. (remember I could have
stolen the hashing power by hacking into a pool)

Mark Friedenbach suggested headers first where the block header and
block contents are propagated around the network separately. What that
results in has a few different scenarios:

1) Fee's don't matter and miners aren't forced to validate

This is the scenario we're in right now. The block reward comprises the
supermajority of mining income, and it is possible to mine a block
without first validating the contents of the previous block. When a
miner receives a block header that extends the longest known blockchain
they can immediately switch to it and start mining.

Whether or not doing so is rational is just a matter of what's the
probability that the previous block was invalid? If it was, the miner
mining it just wasted 25BTC, $12.5k, so you can be almost sure it is
valid and you don't need to wait. Of course, if you then find a block,
you can pull the same trick all over again and the next guy might be
mining on top of two blocks they haven't validated, and so on.

Obviously this presents a very nasty failure mode if the majority of
miners follow this behavior and a block is invalid, or even just gets
lost. Similarly in the majority scenario there's no direct incentive to
actually propagate your blocks - they'll still get accepted to the main
chain anyway.

That said, small and large miners make roughly the same amount as the
block reward dominates and blocks of any size will get confirmations
fairly quickly.


2) Fee's do matter and miners aren't forced to validate

Now transaction fees represent a non-trivial portion of a miner's
income. Centralization incentives would depend on to what extent fees do
matter. Again, there's some nasty failure modes possible. That large,
slow-to-propagate blocks still get confirmed, yet small miners can't
mine transaction fees is likely a major centralization incentive.

3) Miners are forced to validate

Or at least, we can force miners to actually have the previous block.
Andrew Miller's Permacoin is one approach; some varients of UTXO
commitments have this as a side-effect too. On the one hand this solves
the really nasty failure modes that headers-first has; on the other hand
you're back to the centralization incentives we have right now.


What's important however to remember is that any attempt at saying
things like "[A]s soon as [Miners] receive and process the contents of
block A, they switch to that." - as Mark suggested(2) - doesn't belong
in an economic analysis as such rules are unenforcable. For instance
that'd suggest that in the forced-validation headers-first scenario a
large miner who received a block header, then found block themselves,
would switch to mining the block they *didn't* find simply because they
"got the header first". Obviously this is not economically rational for
them to do so they won't, leading to the same centralization incentives
as always.

As for why that's economically irrational: so the large miner finds that
second block and broadcasts it around the network. Do you the small
miner keep mining on the shorter chain just because the large miner
broke the gentlemans agreement to respect header times? Of course not,
time is relative and you have no idea whether or not anyone else is
doing so. If you mine on the shorter chain you're side is going to need
to find two blocks to catch up - not likely. Secondly you risk forking
the network due to a consensus failure, say by a divergent times the
headers were received.

1) http://cs.umd.edu/%7Eamiller/permacoin.pdf

-- 
'peter'[:-1]@petertodd.org
0000000000000000278031f86c71265f6eaf1fe9ce6cc831dc4f956676a7a7f7

[-- Attachment #2: Digital signature --]
[-- Type: application/pgp-signature, Size: 685 bytes --]

  parent reply	other threads:[~2014-04-23 15:06 UTC|newest]

Thread overview: 21+ messages / expand[flat|nested]  mbox.gz  Atom feed  top
     [not found] <mailman.122233.1398039406.2207.bitcoin-development@lists.sourceforge.net>
2014-04-21  1:30 ` [Bitcoin-development] Economics of information propagation Jonathan Levin
2014-04-21  3:58   ` Mark Friedenbach
2014-04-21  4:06     ` Peter Todd
2014-04-21  4:44       ` Daniel Lidstrom
2014-04-21  5:46         ` Daniel Lidstrom
2014-04-21 11:34       ` Tier Nolan
2014-04-21 13:04         ` Jorge Timón
2014-04-21 15:40       ` Ashley Holman
2014-04-21 15:58         ` Alan Reiner
2014-04-21 16:00       ` Mark Friedenbach
2014-04-21 16:22         ` Paul Lyon
2014-04-21 16:38           ` Mark Friedenbach
2014-04-21 16:39             ` Mike Hearn
2014-04-21 16:45         ` Jonathan Levin
2014-04-23  2:54   ` Tom Harding
2014-04-23 15:05   ` Peter Todd [this message]
     [not found]     ` <CAOe4Ui=OaVLvh0vUnNv-1j41YB4B2x896DQ5b6xt4oUJ5oLPFg@mail.gmail.com>
2014-05-02 11:48       ` [Bitcoin-development] Block collision resolution using the DECOR protocol and Bonneau's Kickbacks problem Sergio Lerner
2014-05-02 12:00         ` Sergio Lerner
     [not found]           ` <CAOe4UimBEe4t1Z41du3r8pQUOmzd_1V_aESizuiH2U6uvN9nFA@mail.gmail.com>
2014-05-05 19:45             ` Sergio Lerner
2014-05-05 20:27               ` Ittay
2014-05-07  4:31             ` [Bitcoin-development] DECOR+ Better block selection rule Sergio Lerner

Reply instructions:

You may reply publicly to this message via plain-text email
using any one of the following methods:

* Save the following mbox file, import it into your mail client,
  and reply-to-all from there: mbox

  Avoid top-posting and favor interleaved quoting:
  https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Posting_style#Interleaved_style

* Reply using the --to, --cc, and --in-reply-to
  switches of git-send-email(1):

  git send-email \
    --in-reply-to=20140423150555.GE19430@savin \
    --to=pete@petertodd.org \
    --cc=bitcoin-development@lists.sourceforge.net \
    --cc=bitcoin-research@lists.cs.princeton.edu \
    --cc=jonathan.levin@sant.ox.ac.uk \
    /path/to/YOUR_REPLY

  https://kernel.org/pub/software/scm/git/docs/git-send-email.html

* If your mail client supports setting the In-Reply-To header
  via mailto: links, try the mailto: link
Be sure your reply has a Subject: header at the top and a blank line before the message body.
This is a public inbox, see mirroring instructions
for how to clone and mirror all data and code used for this inbox