Here you go Tom!
https://www.scribd.com/doc/276849939/On-the-Nature-of-Miner-Advantages-in-Uncapped-Block-Size-Fee-MarketsDaniele Pinna, Ph.DOn Thu, Aug 27, 2015 at 12:59 AM, Tom Harding <tomh@thinlink.com> wrote:
Thanks for posting this. I'm very interested to read your paper when it is available.On 8/26/2015 3:22 PM, Daniele Pinna via bitcoin-dev wrote:I don't get how it's very risky to have the Mike and Gavin redirect the course of the bitcoin protocol but it's totally fine to consider complex miner voting protocols as a hard fork option.
I believe that this community has not given due weight to the analysis proposed by Peter__R on the existence of fee markets with uncapped max blocksizes. The critiques made toward his work were in no way definitive and discussion just stopped. Is it the math that bothers people?
If his work stands the test of scrutiny, then a controlled raising of the max blocksize in the interim to ease into the fee market dynamic described is the best option. Possibly a stepwise BIP101 where the community hardforks every two years until we all trust the fee market dynamics.
The main critique to uncapped max blocksizes which I've heard stems from our incapacity to quantify the advantages that large miners have over smaller ones. As I will show in an upcoming paper, these advantages do not stem from the act of propagating large blocks but rather from the block subsidies which allow miners to mine unnecessary large blocks irregardless of the fees contained therein. One typical example is Peter Todd's suggested attack whereby a miner creates a massive block filled with spam transactions that pay himself solely to slow down the rest of the network and gain an advantage. Putting aside the increased orphan risk arising from the propagation of such a large block, this attack would never be viable if it weren't for the existence of current block subsidies.
As such, exponential increases to the max blocksize make perfect sense since the block reward decreases exponentially also. All arguments invoking rates of technological advances (see Gavin's original posts) don't mean anything. Rational miners will NOT be incentivized to mine gargantuan spam filled blocks in the presence of a vanishing block reward.
I truly hope this matter gets the consideration it deserves. Particularly with the upcoming scaling workshops.
Dpinna
On Aug 21, 2015 11:35 PM, "Daniele Pinna" <daniele.pinna@gmail.com> wrote:"I ran some simulations, and if blocks take 20 seconds to propagate, a
network with a miner that has 30% of the hashing power will get 30.3% of the blocks."Peter_R's analysis of fee markets in the absence of blocksize limits [1] shows that the hashrate advantage of a large miner is a side-effect of coinbase subsidization. As the block rewards get smaller, so will large miner advantages. An easy way to think about this is as follows:
Currently, the main critique of larger blocksizes is that we'll connected miners can cut out smaller miners by gratuitously filling up blocks with self-paying transactions. This only works because block subsidies exist. The moment block rewards become comparable to block TX fees, this exploit ceases to be functional.
Basically, large miners will still be forced to move full blocks, but it will go against their interest to fill them with spam since their main source of income is the fees themselves. As a result, large miners (unlike smaller ones) will lose the incentive to mine an un full block this evening the playing field.
In this context, large blocksizes as proposed by BIP100-101 hope to stimulate the increase of TX fees by augmenting the network's capacity. The sooner block rewards become comparable to block fees, the sooner we will get rid of mine centralization.
Dpinna